Changes

Financial approaches

4,747 bytes added, 13:18, 13 November 2008
no edit summary
Improving local access to micro-credit is essential to enhance private sector involvement. Requires good regulatory framework because there is a large difference in the performance of micro-credit organizations. (http://www.microcreditsummit.org/papers/fundspaperfinal.htm#4.7). High potential as opportunities for private sector involvement in sector are growing
 
Limited access to venture capital often restricts small private sector to expand
 
Risk capital needed for further experiments; quality insurance. Often paid through local NGOs. Since the 1980s over 7,500 different types of small family businesses have received credit from the Orangi project in Karachi, with good repayment
(http://www.oppinstitutions.org). In Bangladesh, Burkina Faso, Ghana, Peru and Senegal the private sector supply of latrine parts, construction and sale of soap has been supported, not by micro-credit but by social mobilization programs that increase the demand for the products. These programs are funded by governments and external agencies
(http://www.wsscc.org/pdf/publication/Sanitationisabusiness.pdf). Potential exists in removing a barrier for private sector to grow
 
== Fighting Corruption ==
Significant in the past and applied by various funding agencies including national governments, foreign donors and even NGOs. Now discouraged, with a paradigm shift towards cost sharing because of overall costs involved and to enhance ownership. Leveraging public resources is seen as a key component towards increased financial sustainability
(http://planningcommission.nic.in/plans/mta/mta-9702/mta-ch20.pdf).
 
People receive facilities as a gift
 
In the past, governments often provided 50% to 100% subsidies for household latrines, which tended to ignore or even ‘crowd out’ household resources. It was a typically supply- driven approach which often resulted in many unused facilities. This approach is now discouraged, shifting to cost-sharing or no subsidy because of cost involved and to enhance ownership (http://www.wsp.org/publications/af_finsan_mdg.pdf ).
(http://www.lboro.ac.uk/well/resources/Publications/Briefing%20Notes/BN16%20Local%20financing.htm) High potential because people and WPs may have to take expensive loans from local money lenders
Loans made available to households
 
Good potential as people cannot afford paying high investment. Results of loan schemes specifically for sanitation are mixed if the demand for sanitation is low (sometimes poor repayment) but work better for broader schemes (house improvements). Instalment payments make capital investments easier for the poor. The vulnerable poor, (the poorest people) need additional support because they may not be reached (http://www.williams.edu/Economics/neudc/papers/What%20to%20Expect%20from%20Development%20NGOs%20July%209.pdf). Micro credit schemes exist in different contexts, often through local NGOs or with NGOs acting as a guarantor. Cases on sanitation loans show positive repayments in Honduras, but considerable back-logs in Ghana ( http://www.lboro.ac.uk/well//resources/fact-sheets/fact-sheets-htm/mcfs.htm ). High potential because it may be expected that attention for sanitation will create larger market
Experience with OBA is new, but growing and interesting. The difference with other subsidies is that OBAs are targeted for example to the poorest families (Cambodia) or to the poorest neighbourhoods (Paraguay) clarifying why subsidy is given and they are performance-based. The provider largely self-finances the service, receiving reimbursement mostly after the verification of successful delivery. The latter may reduce possibilities for small providers with limited capital. A bonus-malus approach might be more feasible, perhaps linked to longer-term system performance. (http://www.gpoba.org/documents/OBApproaches_What_is_OBA.pdf).
 
== Partial Subsidies in latrine programmes ==
 
Users contribute in cash or kind or pay connection fee.
 
Good approach to enhance ownership. Also needed for replacement. Some examples of no-subsidy for hardware, but poorest sections may require subsidy. The governments of India and Bangladesh suspended subsidies because they did not reach the poor but then re-introduced them at lower levels (the equivalent of about USD 10) in order to reach the poorest of the poor. Management of subsidies remains a challenge. In Ouagadougou (Burkina Faso): a surtax on water supply is applied by ONEA, an autonomous public water and sanitation company, to subsidize on-site sanitation facilities (25% contribution and supervision of trained masons). 20,000 facilities have been constructed in schools and households. Management of funds presents difficulties, but approach was extended to other towns (http://www.wupafrica.org/toolkit/resources/pdf-files/good_practices/good_practice_Africa.pdf) Good potential to reach the poorer sections of society
 
== Revenue financed expansion ==
(http://www.chinadevelopmentbrief.com/node/248). High potential because of growing access also of poorer groups to credits and remittances of overseas workers
People investing individually or jointly in sanitation
 
Widely used but often poor quality because of weak management and supply chain and particularly because many toilet technologies are unaffordable for the very poor. Needs better access to micro-finance, information, advice and products. Better access to support / stronger private sector involvement would be very beneficial. Actual examples demonstrating success in leveraging household and community resources for sanitation can be found in countries as diverse as India, Lesotho, Vietnam, Bangladesh, Pakistan and Burkina Faso. (http://www.wsp.org/publications/af_finsan_mdg.pdf). Self-financing is increasingly becoming an issue as more and more externally supported programme pay for the software costs for demand creation but no longer for facilities. High potential because of growing access to funding
(http://www.iadb.org/sds/doc/sgc-GN1930-2-E.pdf and http://www.wsp.org/publications/af_socialfunds.pdf). A recent report carried out by the World Bank's evaluations department found that social funds do not always reach the poorest sections of society and can be subject to political influence. Impact in the WS&H sector has varied and sustainability issues have not been well addressed
(http://www1.worldbank.org/publications/pdfs/15141overview.pdf).
 
 
== Tariff ==
 
Users pay the cost for operation and maintenance
 
Accepted as a rule, but not always covering all costs in sewered systems. Poor often cannot afford the fees. Also used for communal facilities that are managed by group of families, paying monthly rates, for example in Nairobi (http://wupafrica.org/toolkit/resources/caseExamples/narrative-form.html). In South Africa differential tariffs are used to support the poor, and no tariff is charged to families using less than 6000 litters of water per month (http://www.joburg.org.za/services/water3.stm). Potential relates to the need to sustain services
59
edits